In recent weeks a fair
amount of discussion in the news has focused on the high price of
drugs. Some of that is attributable to the high price Gilead
Pharmaceuticals set for Solvadi, as mentioned in my last post. Last
week, the Massachusetts Biotechnology Council "MassBio"
issued a report which warned that the increasing pressure on drug
prices along with the overall push to contain healthcare costs could
threaten the future growth of the biotechnology industry and the rate
of innovation in the pharmaceutical industry.1
For many years, the major pharmaceutical companies and their trade
association, now known as PhRMA,2
have been engaged in a reasonably successful effort to convince the
American public and their elected representatives that the high cost
of many drugs is the result of the very high costs of drug
development, which is frequently estimated at $1.2 billion to bring a
new drug to market. I don't want to use this post to debate that
$1.2 billion dollar figure. Drug discovery and development is a very
expensive process, with high costs and many failures, which may well
bring the total costs per new drug approval to $1.2 billion.
However, I begin my course on FDA Law by asking students "What
determines the high cost of drugs?" The success of the PhRMA
public relations effort is reflected in the very large percentage of
students who do indeed answer, "The high cost of developing new
drugs." I then proceed to give them their first lesson on
pharmaceutical policy-- which is that the market for pharmaceuticals
is like almost every market in our essentially free market U.S.
economy. This means that sellers set the price of their goods at
what the market will bear.
This does not mean that
the high cost of drug development has no relationship to the price of
drugs, just that it does so in a relatively indirect way:
pharmaceutical companies will not embark on a drug development
program unless their analysis shows that their ultimate sales
revenues will provide a reasonable return on investment on their very
sizable investment in drug development overall. In other words,
major pharmaceutical companies are generally not interested in
working on drug development programs that, if successful in reaching
the market, will generate less than a $1 billion in annual sales. A
billion-dollar drug represented the threshold for the
"blockbuster"drug category in the eighties and most of the
nineties, and every biotech company executive knew that big pharma
would not be interested in hearing about drugs with smaller expected
revenues. In the seventies and eighties, drug sales revenues
generally achieved blockbuster levels by selling a "modestly"
expensive drug (for example a new $1500 per patient per year
antihypertensive) to a very large number of patients (often a million
or more patients). So the earlier antihypertensives, the first
statins, and the first SSRI antidepressants, all sold for prices that
were very modest by today's standards, but were sold to very large
numbers of patients. However, it has become increasingly difficult
to develop drugs for these kinds of large patient populations, so the
second method of achieving enormous annual revenues, pioneered to a
significant extent by Genzyme, is to sell a drug at unheard of high
prices to even a small patient population. A drug that sells for
$150,000 per patient per year can be enormously profitable even when
the market is 10,000 patients. With the increasing difficulty of
developing drugs for very large patient indications, this second
model of drug pricing has become increasingly dominant, and with it
has come more and more scrutiny of drug pricing and drug company
profits.
These first two aspects
of drug pricing and the pharmaceutical marketplace are relatively
uncomplicated. First, drug prices are set in the marketplace.
Second, the high cost of drug development has made it unattractive to
develop drugs that do not have enormous potential revenues. Neither
of these two assertions would be a surprise to any pharmaceutical
company executive nor is either partricularly controversial. And
there is not any real debate over the logical conclusion: the
revenues required in order for a major pharmaceutical company to
greenlight a drug development program can only be achieved by very
high prices if the target population is not very large. The third
major aspect of drug pricing and the pharmaceutical marketplace,
which will be discussed next, is more complicated to explain and more
controversial: drug companies do not compete extensively, if at all,
on price.
The prices of brand
name pharmaceuticals in a class of drugs, such as the statins for
cholesterol reduction, or the proton pump inhibitors for
gastroesophageal reflux disease (heartburn), do not come down much,
if at all, when one of the other pharmaceuticals in that class
becomes available as a generic at a small fraction of the cost. A
30-day supply of Crestor (a potent statin) costs just under $200 at
Costco (one of the lowest cost retail pharmacies in the U.S.), while
the Costco price for a 30-day supply of Pfizer's branded Lipitor
varies from $165 to $235 depending on the dose.3
At the same time, Costco sells a 30 day supply of the generic
version of Lipitor, atorvastatin, for between $15.59 and $20.33,
again depending on the dosage. This generic price, like most generic
prices, is less than 10% of the cost of the brand name drug, in this
case higher doses of Lipitor. So Pfizer is clearly not competing
with the generic versions of its Lipitor; nor has Astra Zeneca's
Crestor come down substantially in price in response to the
introduction of generic Lipitor. Crestor continues to command a high
price even since Lipitor became available as a generic. This is
despite the fact that a heavily funded Astra Zeneca SATURN study
failed to show that Astra Zeneca's drug was superior to Lipitor on
Astra Zeneca's carefully chosen surrogate endpoint of percent
atheroma volume (PAV) measured by intravascular ultrasound.4
Similarly,
Costco
sells
Nexium for much more than 10 times the price of Omeprazole, the
generic version
of Prilosec,
which has the same active ingredient in a lower dose. The
high prices of Crestor and Nexium
in the face of similarly effective generic compeetition clearly
illustrate
the fact
that the pharmaceutical marketplace is not
one
in which price is
the major point of competition
(although there is
some competition on pricing at the margin in deals between
pharmaceutical companies and the pharmaceutical benefits managers of
the major health insurors).
If
pharmaceutical companies are not competing on price, and
pharmaceutical prices for branded drugs are not determined by the
costs of developing or producing the drug, what is
the nature of competition in the pharmaceutical marketplace? It
would be nice if the answer to that question was that drug companies
are competing on the basis of their absolute contributions to
patients'
health;
but, in the great majority of cases
that
isn't true either. In
the example of Crestor and Lipitor, discussed above, both drugs were
marketed heavily
by promoting their
ability
to reduce levels of
LDL (low density lipoproteins, or "bad" cholesterol),
which is a primary endpoint for evaluating such drugs.
And when Astra
Zeneca funded
the SATURN trial in an attempt to show that the slightly greater
reduction in LDL achieved by Crestor would translate into a greater
reduction in the amount of plaque inside arteries, the trial showed
that it did not. And, even more important for purposes of this
discussion, the relationship between that endpoint and the "real"
endpoint of a reduction in cardiovascular morbidity and mortality was
not tested, almost certainly because any difference in that endpoint
would be very, very small between the two drugs, and almost
impossible to demonstrate in a trial of even several thousand
patients.
Another
rather
interesting
illustration of the strange and complex way
the pharmaceutical
marketplace focuses on factors other than price and effecticacy, is
provided by the
competition between three high-cost rheumatoid arthritis (RA)
drugs--Humira,
Remicade, and Enbrel--which
all work on the same pharmaceutical target in the body. These
drugs work
by blocking or reducing the activity of TNF (tumor necrosis factor),
a circulating protein that is a key driver of the inflammation
pathway. Inflammation is, of course, the underlying pathology in a
number of diseases, from rheumatoid arthritis to inflammatory bowel
diseases such as Crohn's disease.
A recent study found NO difference between these drugs in terms of
their safety and effectiveness in treating RA.5
That's right--
there is NO difference in how well these three drugs work
or
their relative safety.
And the prices of all three drugs are high.
One industry source estimates
the average per patient cost of all three drugs at approximately
$20,000
per year.6
While all three drugs are priced very similarly, Humira and Remicade
each
had total 2012
sales of
just under
$2 billion per year
(for
the RA market only, not total sales for all uses
of those drugs),
while Enbrel's 2012 sales in RA lagged well behind at
about $938
million.7
So
how are these drugs competing? One answer seems to be that they are
competing on patient convenience (Humira wins on that) and
reimbursement (Remicade
has the advantage,
at least for Medicare patients). Humira is packaged in two
different
dosages
in pre-filled
syringes for patient self-injection subcutaneously. Remicade is
administered in physicians'
offices or clinical settings, as an intravenous infusion,
which is not convenient for patients, but
which means that Medicare reimburses the drug's cost for all Medicare
patients.8
Enbrel, like Humira, is a subcutaneous injectable drug.
However
it is not pre-packaged
in convenient doses, but must be properly stored and then mixed prior
to injection, which can be done by some patients after appropriate
instruction. This is obviously much less convenient than Humira, and
because it is not presumptively administered by a physician, as is
Remicade, Medicare reimbursement is not automatic. The result is that
Enbrel's sales lag well behind its two main competitors, despite its
equal safety and efficacy.
The
pharmaceutical marketplace is a complicated one, where patents
provide a signficant measure of protection against competition based
largely on price, where data on the real benefit of competing drugs
in terms of patients' health is often lacking, and where
drugs
sometimes
compete
on
other factors such as convenience and reimbursement. When
all
drugs are equally convenient, as is the case of the statins and most
other once-a-day pills, the competition is driven by marketing, often
focusing on non-primary health endpoints, such as marginal
incremental reductions in LDL levels. Despite the lack of any
evidence whatsoever that Crestor is "better" for patients'
health than atorvastatin, the generic Lipitor, Astra Zeneca managed
to sell over $5 billion dollars worth of Crestor in 2013, the first
full year after generic Lipitor became available! No wonder
marketing budgets for pharmaceutical companies are even greater than
their R&D costs.9
So
to return to the question of why
pharmaceutical
companies set such high prices for drugs, the answer is
that
it is a bit complicated, but mostly because they can.
1
MassBio, Impact 2020: Advancing
Massachusetts Leadership in the Life Sciences for Patients,
online at
http://www.massbio.org/news/450massbio_issues_impact_2020_report_outlining_the/news_detail
(visited April 11,
2014).
2 Pharmaceutical
Research and Manufacturers of America- the "R" was added
with an eye to public relations decades ago when the organization
was simply PMA.
3 All
Costco pharmacy prices quoted in this post were obtained online on
April 11, 2014 at
http://www2.costco.com/Pharmacy/DrugInformation.aspx?p=1 .
4 http://clinicaltrials.gov/ct2/show/study/NCT00620542
. See also Nicholls et al., Effect
of Two Intensive Statin Regimens on Progression of Coronary Disease,
365 New Eng J of Med 2078, December 1, 2011.
Michael O'Riordan,
Rosuvostatin and Atorvastatin Equally Regress
Atherosclerosis,
Medscape Pharmacists Heartwire, November 15, 2011 at
http://www.medscape.com/viewarticle/753603 visited April 11th, 2014.
5Jeffrey
D Greenberg et al, A
Comparative Effectiveness Study of Adalimumab, Etanercept and
Infliximab in Biologically Naive and Switched Rheumatoid Arthritis
Patients,
71(7) Annals of Rheumatic Diseases, 1134-1142
(2012).
6
Peter
Geschek,
Fierce
Competition in the RA Market, Seeking
Alpha, June 1, 2012 (online at
http://seekingalpha.com/article/632311-fierce-competition-in-the-ra-market).
7
Id.
8
Department of Health & Human Services (DHHS), Self-Administered
Drug Exclusion Lists, CMS
Manual, Pub 100-02 Medicare Benefit Policy, June 20, 2008.
9
Science
Daily, York University, Big
Pharma Spends More On Advertising Than Research And Development,
Study Finds,
January 7, 2008, available at
http://www.sciencedaily.com/releases/2008/01/080105140107.htm
My paper, which criticizes the FDA's decision to withdraw approval of original OxyContin, points to the potential for higher-priced drugs as one of many adverse consequences of the decision (based in part on Purdue's continued monopoly). I suppose I'll have to cite you (contra)!
ReplyDeleteLet us not discount the theory of high cost of drug development. But, to give patent and make it exclusive for 20 years is just mind numbing and amounts to exploitation. Everyone knows that the cost of drug development is recovered in short period may be two or three years. so, giving patent for five years for any new drug entity would be justified. Moreover, the pricing of the drugs ought to be cost base. i.e. material cost+research cost+conversion cost + packing + marketing cost. It may be review every two year and increased to meet the rising costs.
ReplyDeleteOur bad luck is that there are several politicians who are on payroll of Pharma companies (of course not directly). That skews the Pharmaceutical Policy of every country.
It is absolutely necessary to amend International Patent Laws and Treaties to restrict patent period for five years only. At least in healthcare and pharmaceutical sector.
Jayendra Pandya, Mumbai India
Jayendra,
ReplyDeleteI appreciate your reading of the post and your input. I think that the market incentives for drug development aren't perfect, but can be improved without tinkering much with patent term. The effective term of patents in pharmaceuticals is now about 14 years, and has increased in the past decade or so from 12 years. I think treating inventions for life saving drugs LESS favorably then cell phone inventions, for example, would do more harm then good.
Social media marketing is the best effective marketing. But people do not do social media marketing just thinking about the cost. But they don't know if they compare with effectiveness of social media marketing then it cost nothing. Social media marketing cost
ReplyDeleteMd Jasim,
DeleteI think there are many issues with social media marketing generally, but in the case of Rx drugs it is extremely dangerous. The last thing we need is less evidence-based use of pharmaceuticals, and it is impossible to see how social media marketing would increase evidence-based prescribing and use.