There are two stories in the recent
pharma news that are completely unrelated. In this week's post I
will ponder their possible relationship. In the first story, Damien
Garde of FiercePharma reported that a highly-regarded biotech
industry analyst, Geoffrey Porges, is highly critical of Amgen's
ambitious and risky R&D efforts.1
In the second story, also in FiercePharma, Eric Palmer reported that
a court in Delhi, India, has ordered Roche and Cipla to enter into
mediation of their dispute over the patent on Roche's cancer drug
Tarceva.2
In the first story, on Amgen, there are
two very interesting points made by Porges, as reported by Garde.
The first is that over the last 10 years Amgen has spent $30 billion
in R&D and that the resulting drugs have brought in only $15
billion in cumulative revenue. The second major point is that:
Compared
to its Big Biotech peers, the company has a pipeline particularly
loaded with what Porges terms "breakthrough" assets:
first-in-class agents with unproven targets and unknown safety
profiles. At the moment, 80% of Amgen's pipeline is made up of such
breakthrough therapies, according to Bernstein's numbers, compared to
just 33% for Vertex Pharmaceuticals and 38% each for Gilead Sciences
and Celgene
[stock symbols omitted].3
In
last week's post Profit
or Drugs? (June
9, 2014),
I discussed the issue underlying Porges's critique of Amgen and took
the position that the goal of pharmaceutical policy is
to make the rewards from high-risk research ("breakthrough"
in Porges's terms) more attractive than the returns from
comparatively low-risk research ("me-too" drugs in
pharmaceutical policy terms). However, my purpose in highlighting
the Porges/Amgen story is not to defend the choices Amgen has made in
allocating its R&D efforts or criticize Porges's analysis of
Amgen's strategy
(although it would seem more appropriate to measure the payoff of a
decade's R&D budget by profits in the decade following, rather
than the decade in which the R&D was performed).
Rather, it is simply to
use
the Porges/Amgen story to illustrate a point that would seem obvious
but all too often is either minimized or even denied by
pharmaceutical industry critics: High-risk
pharmaceutical research is indeed very expensive and not at all
certain to pay off.
In
the second story, concerning the Indian court's order directing Roche
and Indian drug company
Cipla to mediate their dispute over Roche's Tarceva, the background
to the dispute is
familiar to most persons interested in pharmaceutical policy. The
Roche-Cipla dispute is just a small part of the broader issues
of access to expensive and important drugs in developing countries
and the barriers to access presented by patents and international
agreements concerning the enforceability of patents. India, in
particular, has brought the patent issue to the fore in recent months
because it has a pharmaceutical industry that is technically capable
of copying such drugs and because its highest court has issued
extremely controversial decisions on the validity of some of the
patents in question.4
My purpose in this post is not to delve into the underlying merits
of the Tarceva patent, or even to examine the more general question
of whether the Indian Supreme Court's approach to obviousness in
pharmaceutical patents is either appropriate or legitimate under
international trade law.5
Instead I will attempt to use Amgen's R&D budget and the Indian
patent issues
to
help illuminate the relationship between pharmaceutical companies'
risks,
prices, and the widely-recognized human right of access to
"essential" drugs.6
In
this blog I have argued that pharmaceutical companies set prices for
their drugs based on their estimate of what the market will bear and
therefore
high prices for drugs are not really the result of the high cost of
pharmaceutical research and development (see my posts of April 12th
and 18th). However, as Geoffrey Porges's critique of Amgen shows,
investors do expect blockbuster profits from drug companies, and the
very high prices that "the market will bear" for
life-saving drugs are the way investor expectations are ultimately
satisfied. And, of course, without investors willing to put money
into biotech and pharmaceutical companies, there would be no R&D.
That leaves us with the question of how to satisfy the human right
to "essential" medicines when such a large percentage of
the world's population cannot afford to pay high prices for the drugs
they desperately need. To answer that question we must first answer
two others. First, if pharmaceutical companies charge what the
market will bear, why are they charging more than the market will
bear in the Indian market, or the sub-Saharan African
market, or the South American market? Second, how are we to fulfill
the human right to optimal attainable health, particularly when that
goal entails the use of patented pharmaceuticals?
As
to the first question, if drug prices in Britain, for example, are
lower than prices in the U.S.,7
why are prices in India not proportionately lower still? The answer
is largely because pharmaceutical companies are concerned that by
making expensive drugs widely available,
at
very low prices in very-low-income countries, those drugs will be
diverted into a "gray
market" in higher income countries, with the potential to
significantly reduce profits on those drugs in countries where they
can, in fact, be sold at a significant profit.8
As to the second question, how are we to fulfill the human right to
optimal attainable health, the answer must be by collective
responsibility in the developed world. Quite simply, we ought not to
place the burden of satisfying the right to health primarily on the
pharmaceutical industry of the developed world any more than we place
the burden of satisfying the right to basic nutrition primarily on
the agricultural industry of the developed world.9
Remember
the investors who
expect blockbuster profits from pharmaceutical companies? If we
place the burden of human health on the pharmaceutical industry, then
we put the pharmaceutical industry at a disadvantage relative to, for
example, Take-Two Interactive Software, Inc., the company which sells
Grand-Theft Auto V, a highly profitable product that is utterly
devoid of any obligation to persons in developing countries.10
Investors, as a rule, go where the profits are. It is not in the
interest of global health to send investors scurrying from Amgen to
Take-Two Interactive. Whatever happens to Roche's patent dispute in
India, we should hope that Roche's profits are sufficiently
attractive to investors that Roche's R&D budgets can continue and
even grow. For many years I have been paraphrasing the famous line
from The Graduate and telling my seminar,
"Just one word, Benjamin. Biotechnology." I would really
rather not be compelled to change that to,
"Just
three words,
Benjamin. Violent Video Games."
1
Damian
Garde,
Analyst:
Amgen's Moonshot R&D Spending Is Bad For Business,
in
FiercePharma,
available
at http://www.fiercebiotech.com/node/371216/print
(June 13, 2014),
hereinafter "Garde-Amgen."
2
Eric
Palmer,
Roche
and Cipla are ordered to mediate in a new twist on Indian IP fight,
in
FiercePharma,
available
at http://www.fiercepharma.com/node/159661/print (June 13, 2014).
3
Garde-Amgen supra note 1.
4 See
e.g. Novartis AG v. Union of
India, (2007) 4 MADRAS L.J. 1153, available
at
http://www.scribd.com/doc/456550/High-Court-order-Novartis-Union-of-India
(concerning Novartis's Gleevec, widely considered to be a
breakthrough cancer drug).
5 For
those interested in an analysis of the Novartis/India issue see
Linda L. Lee, Trials
and TRIPS-
ulations: Indian
Patent Law and Novartis AG v. Union of India,
23 Berkeley
Tech. L. J.
Article 12 (February 2014) available at
http://scholarship.law.berkeley.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1728&context=btlj.
6
World
Health Organization, Access
to essential medicines as part of the right to health,
available
at
http://www.who.int/medicines/areas/human_rights/en/ (visited June
15, 2014).
7
Kai Ruggeri, Ellen Nolte, Pharmaceutical pricing: The use
of external reference pricing,
Rand Europe, available at
http://www.rand.org/content/dam/rand/pubs/research_reports/RR200/RR240/RAND_RR240.pdf
(2013).
8
Keith E. Maskus, Parallel
Imports In Pharmaceuticals: Implications For Competition And Prices
In Developing Countries, Final
Report to World Intellectual Property Organization (Draft: April
2001) available at
http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/about-ip/en/studies/pdf/ssa_maskus_pi.pdf.
9 I
first made this point in my remarks at a symposium on international
issues in intellectual property protection: Symposium,
Legal
Reform: The Role Of Public Institutions And Legal Culture,
35
Cal. W. Int'l L.J. 237 (Spring 2005).
10
John Rawls, A
Theory of Justice (Cambridge,
Mass.: The Belknap Press of
Harvard
University Press, 1971)
provides a framework for thinking about all issues concerning the
relationship between those with talents, whether video-gaming or
biochemistry, and those who are least-advantaged, such as critically
ill persons in the developing world.
No comments:
Post a Comment