There are two stories
in The New York Times
that, although not directly related, are the basis for today's post.
The first, by Andrew Ross Sorkin, Do Drug Companies Make Drugs, or
Money?, appeared
in the Business Section on page B1 on June 3, 2014. The
second, by Andrew Pollock, New System for Treating Cancer Seen as
Hopeful, appeared on the same
page of The New York Times on the same day. Sorkin's provocatively
titled article focused on Valeant Pharmaceutical International's
takeover bid for Allergan and on Valeant's strategy, which Sorkin
characterized as buying pharmaceutical companies with revenues
produced by active and successful pharmaceutical research programs
and then increasing profits by cutting back on R&D. Sorkin's
article, as the title indicated, posited a tension between focusing
on rewarding investors with
increased profits and investing in the development of new and
innovative therapies. My purpose in highlighting Sorkin's article
alongside Pollock's is not to take issue with Sorkin's analysis of
Valeant's business strategy, but to respond to the article's title
question. The answer is that pharmaceutical companies'
primary obligation is to their shareholders and that means their
primary objective is to reward those investors with increased
profits--that is,
"make money." However, as Pollock's article about a very
promising new class of anti-cancer drugs illustrates, developing new
and medically-valuable
therapeutics is a major, although not the only, way that
pharmaceutical companies seek to earn those increased profits. Now
if all I had to say about these two articles is that pharmaceutical
companies, like all other businesses, attract and reward investors by
making profits and developing important new drugs is a way of making
large profits, I would only be stating the obvious.
To
me, the fundamental question of pharmaceutical policy is this: How
can we use the complex legal and regulatory environment in which
pharmaceutical companies operate (and here for this purpose I exclude
generic pharmaceutical companies) so that making innovative and
important new drugs is the best
and virtually the only way
for those companies to earn the substantial profits required to
reward their investors and ensure a future investment stream? In
"What is Pharmaceutical Policy and What Is Its Goal?", the
post at the top of this blog,
I highlighted patent law, the FDA, and the various insurance systems
that subsidize some portion of patients' pharmaceutical costs as all
having a significant role in steering pharmaceutical companies'
development efforts. Thus those areas of law and regulation, as well
as others, are responsible for the results of pharmaceutical
companies' development efforts--the mix of the amazing and the
marginal, first-in-class breakthroughs like Glivec and me-too1
drugs like Nexium. The premise of this blog is that we can have a
much better mix of drugs--representing
more innovation and providing
more health--for the same
overall cost or even at a lower cost than we do today.
Each
of the major areas of law and regulation can be tweaked to produce
overall better results. For example, patent law, as it is currently
interpreted by the United States Patent and Trademark Office,
encourages narrow pharmaceutical patents that provide ample room for
marginal innovation and me-too drugs. The FDA's current application
of its oversight of the drug development process does not push drug
companies to determine the subgroup of patients who are truly
benefitted by a drug. Instead, drug companies
narrow the patient population
being studied (which defines a drug's labeled indication and
potential market) only enough to produce a statistically significant
result in clinical trials. If a drug can be shown to be effective in
all adults with major depressive disorder, that will become the
labeled indication and primary market, even if additional research
would have shown that 30% of that population varies in some
biological dimension that makes the drug wholly ineffective for that
group. As I discussed in my post on "Comparative
Effectivness: A Major Priority for Pharmaceutical Policy" (June
2, 2014), the task of funding the research to identify how well
competing drugs work, and in whom they work best, is largely left to
the government, where adequate funding for that task is very
problematic. As for reimbursement, under the Affordable Care Act,
insurers must offer coverage of at least one drug in every class, and
more if their
state's benchmark plan does so.2
However, each insurer's formulary can vary in structure; and,
the extent to which the insurer's formulary actually encourages
doctors and patients to make optimal choices in deciding on
prescription drug therapy is problematic, at best. So pharmaceutical
companies set out to make money
and a variety of laws and
regulations have a profound impact on how pharmaceutical companies
plan to and actually do earn profits. As Pollock's story
illustrates, the current system does provide the potential for
enormous profits for research and development that leads to
innovative and extraordinarily valuable new drugs. However, it also
leads to extraordinary profits for drugs that provide almost no
innovation or additional value, such as Nexium. The goal is to
adjust the rules so that we get far more of the former and far less
of the latter.
1 "Me-too"
is a term used by many participants in the pharmaceutical law and
policy world to describe the numerous drugs that are very similar to
a highly innovative "first-in-class drug" and enter the
marketplace after the first-in-class drug has been approved. In
turn "first-in-class" drugs work through a "new and
unique mechanism of action for treating a medical condition."
FDA, "2011 Novel New Drugs" available at: www.fda.gov/downloads/Drugs/DevelopmentApprovalProcess/DrugInnovation/ucm293663.pdf.
Generally a new and unique mechanism of action means the drug works
on a new biological target in the body. Me-too drugs work through a mechanism of action previously used to treat the same
condition and often have chemical structures that are very similar
to the first-in-class drug.
2 45
CFR 156.122.
No comments:
Post a Comment