The FDA announced its new efforts to "to
increase competition in the market for prescription drugs" and in my
view it is likely to do little or nothing to affect spending on prescription
drugs in the United States. The first step announced by the FDA is simply that
that the FDA will publish and maintain a list of off-patent branded drugs with
no generics. The second step announced is that the FDA will prioritize review
of ANDAs for generics where there are less than three generics approved for
that drug. The first step is likely to have little impact because it simply
ignores the fact that the major generic companies devote significant resources
to research the patents on the drugs for which they would like to compete,
making the FDA’s effort largely superfluous. The second step is also likely to
do very little. The attractive generic markets draw many entrants while the
less attractive attract far fewer. It is the market size, not the lag in
review, that largely shapes competition in the generic market. No, despite the
periodic and well-publicized spikes
in the price of a small number of generic drugs, the problem with
prescription drug pricing has very little to do with the speed of entry into
the generic market and has much more to do with the marketing-driven sales of
branded drugs. The FDA has proposed nothing in that regard nor is there anything
yet proposed by the Trump Administration in that direction.
Tuesday, June 27, 2017
Monday, June 26, 2017
BIO 2017: Part I ––Virtual Development Is A Reality.
I attended the big BIO Annual Meeting, which I had not
attended for several years, which was held this year in San Diego from June
19-22. As always, BIO is a great place to get a sense of the overall state of
the Pharma world and pick the brains of some very smart people. My perception
of people in the life science world has always been that the great majority are
remarkably willing to share their own knowledge and insights and this year’s
meeting reinforced that perception. It also reinforced my impression that the
biotech industry folks party a good deal harder than the law professors with
whom I generally hang out, but that would be the subject of a different blog.
As longer-term readers of this blog know, I have had a
continuing interest in the topic of biosimilars––particularly in the question
of whether one or more significantly different business models for biosimilar
development would be feasible and more cost-effective from a patient and
insurer perspective. To put this in perspective, we can use the example of Remicade/
infliximab. Remicade is an antibody that binds to the protein TNFα and
prevents TNFα from delivering its inflammation-stimulating message. Remicade
was one of the first TNFα blocking drugs (others include Enbrel and Humira) and
it has been approved for use in a number of severe inflammatory diseases,
including Crohn’s disease, ulcerative colitis, and rheumatoid arthritis. The FDA has already granted Pfizer approval
to market Inflectra,
a biosimilar Remicade (yes, Pfizer the pharmaceutical behemoth, is in the
biosimilars space). If I wanted to start a virtual biosimilar company and
develop my own biosimilar Remicade (why wouldn’t I want to go head to head
in the marketplace with Pfizer?) who are all the people and service providers I
would need? One of my main goals at this year’s BIO meeting was to learn as
much as I could about the availability of the various kinds of expertise and
services that are required to take the development of a biosimilar from a
proposal to an FDA approved product. Could a small, virtual company produce a
biosimilar Remicade that could be approved by the FDA?
The first step in developing a biosimilar is to create a
cell-line (most-likely using Chinese Hamster Ovary, or CHO cells) that has been
engineered to efficiently produce an lgG1:Κ
(that describes the genus of antibody to which infliximab
belongs) protein that is highly similar in structure and activity to the
original Remicade produced by Janssen. This first step requires sophisticated
expertise in protein engineering and analysis. Is this expertise available on a
contract basis? Can I find a CDO or CMO that can start at the very beginning
and provide me with my starting point of a cell-line to begin further
development? The answer I got at BIO2017 was “yes.” There are absolutely
companies out there that will provide me with a cell-line that has been
engineered to produce my biosimilar and that has been analyzed by a variety of
means as being structurally similar, with the correct glycosylation, comparable
affinity for the target protein, and pharmacokinetics in an appropriate in vivo
model. Immunogenicity analysis is a bit more complicated, but it would and
could be begun in the earliest phase of limited human clinical testing.
The second step is hiring the expertise to guide the
development through the regulatory process, from preclinical testing through
clinical testing and the requisite regulatory filings. There was a covey of
CROs (terrible wordplay intended) hawking (insert another groan here) exactly those
capabilities at BIO 2017. At the same time, the actual manufacturing, from pilot-scale
to market-scale, could be contracted for (and likely from the same company that
did the development and analysis of the master cell-line). At the end of the
day (or weeks of RFPs and negotiations) all the steps could absolutely be set
in motion. All the parts necessary to develop, manufacture, and license our
biosimilar Remicade would be in place and all that would remain are a
relatively low risk of failure in the clinic, worries about being sued for
infringement of some number of process patents by Janssen (a flurry of such
biosimilars infringement suits was predicted by retired U.S. District Court
Judge Faith Hochberg at BIO 2017), and finding a buyer or buyers. I’ll discuss the risk of failure,
infringement, and marketing issues in Part II of Virtual Development.
Wednesday, June 14, 2017
More Ado About Prices
It is almost impossible to read the news today without
coming across an article about the high prices of drugs and various approaches
to bringing drug prices down. I have discussed the general problem of drug
prices in previous posts (Drug
Prices and the Pharmaceutical Market, Pharmaceutical
Pricing-- The Story That Just Keeps Going, and What
the Market Will Bear: Pricing Pressures and Pharmaceutical Value). However,
in today’s post I will briefly discuss two very different developments in the
drug-pricing story. The first is a resolution aimed at pricing that was
recommended for adoption by the American Medical Association (AMA) House of
Delegates. The second development is the growing concern over the
difficult-to-gauge gap between the list or “retail” price of drugs and the
actual amounts paid by different payors.
On the first development, the AMA House of Delegates recently
supported the adoption of Resolution 236 Retail Price of Drugs Displayed in Direct-to-Consumer Pharmaceutical
Advertising. The text of the resolution as adopted is brief:
Resolution 236 asks that our American
Medical Association advocate to the applicable Federal agencies (including the
Food and Drug Administration, the Federal Trade Commission, and the Federal
Communications Commission) which regulate or influence direct-to-consumer
advertising of prescription drugs that such advertising should be
required to state the manufacturer’s
suggested retail price of those drugs.
The AMA is a powerful lobbying group, but it raises the
question of whether the FTC or the FDA has any authority to require the
disclosure of retail prices in direct-to-consumer (DTC) advertising of
prescription drugs. My quick response would be no–– neither the FDA nor the FTC
has such authority. The FTC’s Division
of Advertising Practices “protects consumers from unfair or deceptive
advertising and marketing practices that raise health and safety concerns, as
well as those that cause economic injury.” Accordingly, from
the very beginning of DTC prescription drug ads, the FTC has aimed at
ensuring that consumers are not misled or deceived: “In particular, it is
important to protect consumers from deceptive information but not to stifle
truthful information that could benefit consumers.” There is almost no chance
that the FTC would find that an ad is deceptive or misleading because it fails
to state the price of the item advertised. Similarly, the FDA’s focus in
prescription drug advertising also is on ensuring that the ads are not
misleading (and that they do not suggest the product can be used for conditions
for which the FDA has not approved the drug). In my recent post on DTC ads A
Better Balance Between Accelerated Access And High-Priced New Drugs: A New
Conditional Approval Option I made the argument that those ads are
generally misleading with respect to the effectiveness of the advertised drugs.
So while it is significant that the AMA is continuing to express its concern
about prescription drug prices, this particular action by the AMA is not likely
to have any effect at all.
The other development I will briefly discuss in this post is
the growing awareness of the gap between retail prices (such as those the AMA
would like to see disclosed in DTC ads) and the prices actually paid by a
variety of payors (the “price gap”). How big is the price gap? QuintilesIMS
Institute addressed the question in its Annual Report Medicines
Use and Spending in the U.S. (May 2017). The executive summary of the
report began with what is truly the bottom line:
Spending on medicines increased by 5.8%
to $450Bn in 2016, growing at less than half the rate seen in the last two
years, based on invoice prices. After adjusting for estimated rebates and other
price concessions by manufacturers, which continued to rise in 2016, net
spending was $323Bn, up 4.8% over 2015 levels. When adjusted for these
concessions, as well as economic and population growth, medicine spending
increased 2.6% in 2016 and has increased by an average of 1.1% per year since
2006, while the balance of medicines being used has shifted strongly to
specialty medicines from traditional treatments.
The Report then went on to summarize its findings with
respect to year-over-year increases for drugs already in the market:
The average net price for brands
already in the market is estimated to have increased by 3.5% in 2016, up from
2.5% in 2015, while remaining significantly lower than prior years. This reflects
the heightened competition among manufacturers and more aggressive efforts by
health plans and pharmacy benefit managers to limit price growth. Invoice price levels, prior to the impact
of concessions, increased 9.2% in 2016…. [emphasis added.]
What are the takeaways from the
IMSQuintiles Report? The ridiculous annual increases in retail prices for
existing drugs (the 9.2% in the Report) are the attention-grabbing headlines of
a number
of stories on drug prices, but only the starting point for the price
negotiations with payers and pharmacy benefit managers (PBMs). The price gap is
a much more complicated part of the drug pricing story, which is closely linked
to another major part of the pharmaceutical marketplace, the role of PBMs. Back
in March, Bloomberg
BNA reported that Senator Wyden (D.Ore) “proposed legislation that would
force drug middlemen to disclose secret discounts they receive from
manufacturers, a sign of growing scrutiny of the role played by pharmacy
benefit managers in high prices.” Wyden’s proposal, S.637 -
Creating Transparency to Have Drug Rebates Unlocked (C-THRU) Act of 2017 is, as the title suggests, about increasing
transparency in prices (for Medicare Part D drugs), which in theory can lead to
more negotiating power on the buyer side and lead to lower prices overall. This
kind of transparency in the prices actually charged for drugs is very different
from the “transparency” that is the subject of a number
of state laws seeking to require disclosure of the costs of developing
individual drugs. Sarpatwari et al reviewed those initiatives
in The New England Journal of Medicine and pointed out the conceptual and
practical difficulties with “cost of development” disclosure mandates. My own
analysis is that transparency in the actual prices paid, which is the focus of
the Wyden proposal would be helpful. Marketplaces require information to work. While
much of the information needed for the pharmaceutical marketplace to work is
information about the actual effectiveness of a drug, prices paid by other parties
is also extremely useful. The problem of rising drug costs is unlikely to be
solved by information about prices, but it would at least be a step in the
right direction.
Monday, June 12, 2017
U.S. Supreme Court Issues Opinion in Sandoz v. Amgen: A Big Win for Sandoz and Other Biosimilar Applicants.
The U.S. Supreme Court released its much-anticipated ruling
today in the battle between Sandoz and Amgen over Amgen’s biosimilar version of
Sandoz’s Neupogen (filgrastim). Justice
Thomas’s opinion for a unanimous Court was an almost total victory for Amgen. Justice
Breyer issued a very brief one-page opinion concurring in the decision but expressing
his view that in future cases deference should be given to the FDA’s reasonable
interpretation of the Biologics
Price Competition and Innovation Act of 2009 (the Act).
There were two major issues decided by the Court today. The
first was whether or not Sandoz fulfilled the 180-day notice requirement of the
Act when it delivered its original 180-day notice of its intent to market a
biosimilar filgrastim at the time of filing its application with the FDA. The
second major issue decided was whether the Act’s elaborate provisions providing
for exchanges of information (the “patent dance”) is mandatory. In the patent
dance the specifying the biosimilar applicant can provide its manufacturing
information to the reference drug sponsor followed the reference drug sponsor’s
provision of lists of patents it claims
are infringed by the biosimilar applicant
The answer to both these questions favored Sandoz. The
original 180-day notice of intent to market that Sandoz provided at the time of
filing its original application with the FDA was sufficient. No subsequent, second such notice was
required. The relevant language of the opinion on that clause is:
The Federal Circuit held that an
applicant’s biosimilar must already be “licensed” at the time the applicant
gives notice. 794 F. 3d, at 1358.
We disagree. The applicant must give
“notice” at least 180 days “before the date of the first commercial marketing.”
The provision of manufacturing information by the biosimilar
applicant and patent lists by the reference drug sponsor is not mandatory. The
remedy for the biosimilar applicant’s failure to provide the information that the Act provides is that the filing of
the biosimilar application is an act of infringement enabling the reference
drug sponsor to file suit. Here is the relevant language of that portion of the
opinion.
Clause (ii) of §271(e)(2)(C), in
contrast, defines artificial infringement in the situation where an applicant
fails to disclose its application and manufacturing information altogether and
the parties never prepare the §262(l)(3) lists. That clause provides
that the submission of the application represents an act of artificial infringement
with respect to any patent that could have been included on the lists.
The Court did, however, leave a very small opening for Amgen
to snatch victory from the jaws of defeat. While Amgen was not entitled to an automatic
injunction under the biosimilar Act, on remand the U.S. District Court must
determine (again, from Justice Thomas’s opinion):
whether California law would treat
noncompliance with §262(l)(2)(A) as “unlawful.” If the answer is yes,
then the court should proceed to determine whether the BPCIA pre-empts any
additional remedy available under state law for an applicant’s failure to
comply with §262(l)(2)(A) (and whether Sandoz has forfeited any
pre-emption defense, see 794 F. 3d, at 1360, n. 5). The court is also of course
free to address the pre-emption question first by assuming that a remedy under
state law exists.
I would predict the District Court will not issue an
injunction based on California law and Amgen’s only recourse is to continue with
its infringement suit.
Tuesday, June 6, 2017
Good News for Sickle-Cell Patients, But How Will Emmaus Make Money? A Look at the Business Side of Pharmaceutical Policy
BUT, this is one of the most unusual drug development
studies I have seen. While other Orphan Drug makers have taken older compounds
through development and relied on the 7 years of Orphan Drug exclusivity to
return a profit on their investment, L-Glutamine is not just an older compound.
Unlike repurposed older drugs, it is widely available and used as a dietary
supplement. So while Emmaus is to be commended for undertaking the costly and
risky process of establishing the effectiveness of L-Glutamine for Sickle Cell
Disease and will be the only manufacturer allowed to label L-Glutamine for
treating Sickle Cell Disease, they will not be the only manufacturer selling
L-Glutamine in bulk quantities sufficient to treat Sickle Cell Disease. A quick
search online revealed numerous online sellers.
For example,
one online seller is offering 250 grams of L-Glutamine (advertised as
pharmaceutical-grade) for $9.95.
Since the Emmaus studies dosed patients at between 20 to 60 grams a day,
depending on body weight, the 250 grams being sold online would be last between
4 to 12.5 days. Even assuming that most
patients require 60 grams per day, the price for 1800 grams online would be a
bit more than $60 per month. I have not
yet seen an announcement of Emmaus’ intended pricing for their product
post-approval, however, their current
pricing for the same drug, approved for short bowel syndrome, would be over $2000
per month at the higher dose. While
the Rx form is likely to be covered by insurance, it still seems quite possible
that a significant market share could be lost to patients simply buying
L-Glutamine online. That would still be good for patients, but not very good
for Emmaus’ bottom line. It will be very interesting to follow Emmaus’ sales
over the next few years to see whether taking a dietary supplement through the
FDA approval process can actually work for companies as well as patients.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)